Author: A. R. Desai
Publisher: Popular Prakashan, 1990
(First published 1948)
ISBN: 0861320867
Pages:461
When
the Muslims demanded partition of pre-independent India on the basis that
Hindus and Muslims constituted two separate nations, the nationalists were
completely taken aback. The very concept of nationhood in the modern sense was
hardly a century old by then. Civilizational unity of the country stretching
thousands of years was an undisputable fact but the political unity of the
landmass was uncertain for most of the time. India arose as a modern nation
after the British conquest that subjected her to the ignominy of being a colony
to a European power. Nationalism germinated after the rebellion of 1857 and was
spearheaded by various socio-economic groups in many phases. As the economy
underwent a change from feudalism to full-fledged capitalism, the social groups
also changed in texture and content. This book seeks to assess the social
background of Indian nationalism from a Marxian perspective. What sets it apart
from other books is that it was written very close to independence. Akshay
Ramanlal Desai (1915-94) was an Indian sociologist, Marxist and a social
activist. He was professor of sociology at the University of Mumbai. He is
mainly remembered as the author of this book.
Desai
presents a good picture of pre-British India that lived out a sordid existence
under centuries of Islamic rule. The villages which accommodated the bulk of
the population were in a time warp that blindly reproduced the socio-economic
activities it had practiced for millennia. The village was self-sufficient and
was based on agriculture carried out with the primitive plough and bullock
power. A few people were employed in handicrafts by means of simple
instruments. A curious thing to note in this basic economic unit was the
absence of private ownership of land, which was managed by the community
elders. The overlord got his tribute from the produce but had no right of
eviction of individual peasants in case of no or short payment. In this crucial
sense, Indian feudalism was different from the West. National consciousness did
not grow in such an atmosphere of self-contained village societies as it
presupposed common political and economic life. Besides, there was no
significant economic exchange in the form of trade.
The
towns performed somewhat better. Desai claims that the economic and cultural
life of towns was rich and progressive. It had constant contact with the
outside world. Artisans produced articles for the king or other aristocrats for
conspicuous consumption. As long as the feudal system prevailed, there were
takers for their products. When it collapsed, the workers were rendered
jobless. The ruin of urban handicrafts helped to set up exchange relations grow
through markets. The producers adapted to the change in demand and diversified
into articles which are useful for ordinary and rich merchants. The slew of
counterfeit production centres in towns like Agra or Aligarh is a relic of that
distant era. Consequent to this, a weak native merchant capitalist class emerged
in India at the disintegration of Mughal Empire. However, the exchange and
distribution of commodities was only between urban centres.
The
changes wrought by the British after they conquered India form an interesting
part of the narrative. The British conquest was the first of India’s conquests
by a modern nation which had abolished feudalism and created a modern bourgeois
society in its place. But there were vast differences between the systems
existing in India and which existed in Britain. The zamindars had no right of
ownership on the land and performed the function of revenue collectors. The
British swept away this system with Lord Cornwallis’ Permanent Land Settlement
(1793). It converted the revenue-collecting nobles into landlords upon payment
of a fixed amount to the government. In return, this new class of landlords
supported the British thereafter. In the Deccan, it was the small landholders
who proliferated. So they introduced the Ryotwari system in which the
individual cultivator became the owner of the land. In this way, private
property was introduced in India which is the basic requirement of a capitalist
society. The village agricultural output was brought within the sphere of
domestic and foreign markets by trade in grains and cash crops such as indigo,
tea and coffee. This helped the villages to become an organic part of Indian
economy. The author acclaims this as a positive aspect of the British conquest.
The political unity which was enhanced by the exchange-based economic system
set up a capitalist economy in India and nationalism was a byproduct of the
unity of the land politically, socially and economically.
Once
nationalism takes root, it needs to be nurtured. This task was taken up by
English-educated intellectuals who advocated social reform measures such as the
banning of suttee and encouraging
widow remarriage. After the 1857 revolt, the government did not intervene in
religious matters. Very soon movements taking sustenance from India’s perceived
glorious past emerged. Mass participation came about in movements related to
agriculture, trade and demands for representation in the bureaucracy. The plan
for regeneration and restructuring of national agriculture presupposed a
national government which reflected the will of the people. The colonial
government viewed India only as a producer of raw material for British industry
and as a market for their produce. As the nationalists discerned the true
colours of the British administrators, there arose a strong desire among them
to unseat the aliens and bring in a government elected and governed by Indians.
Development of transport, communication and modern education cemented
nationalist ideas.
The
book is authored by a Marxist scholar and he goes on to examine the involvement
of Indian industrialists in the national movement and how the movement was
bankrolled by them. He accuses Gandhi of dancing to the tune of Indian
industry. Indian capitalists began to enter the nationalist movement in the
first decade of the twentieth century. They gravitated to the Congress and
supported the program of Swadeshi and boycott of British goods since it also
served its own class interest. Industrialists strongly supported Gandhi and his
control over the Congress. Wealthy industrialists subsidized such anachronous
schemes as revival of handspun clothing. Moreover, Gandhi opposed the
revolutionary concept of class struggle and instead called for collaboration of
all sections of people. This endeared him to the industrialists. Going a step
further, Desai alleges that the bourgeois leadership of the Congress under
Gandhi was closely aligned to the vested interests like the Zamindari (p.354).
Gandhian mass movements had a pressure value which the capitalists appreciated.
The movements became levers to secure from the British the satisfaction of
their demands such as safeguards for Indian industry and commerce.
The
author’s ideological commitment to Marxism clouds his judgement, colours the
analysis and confounds the results. In his statement that ‘pre-British Indian
education was controlled only by Brahmins and they imparted superstition and
conformity in the pupils’, the entire corpus of Indian knowledge is blackened
as superstition. But on the other hand, ‘Islamic schools were open to all
because of the democratic character of Islam’ (p.138). Clearly, the
Leftist-Islamist nexus is very old and solid. Desai fails to recognise the
civilizational unity that integrated India from the very distant past but
claims that the religio-ideological unity did not overlap into political unity.
He then grudgingly admits that ‘it is true that a conception of unity of India
existed and flourished in pre-British times’, but then qualifies this ‘to be
conceived as the religio-cultural unity of the Hindus’ (p.167). In this
metaphorical twisting of the knife, the entire edifice of Indian unity is
trivialized as naturally occurring among the followers of a common religion! In
addition to this biased rhetoric, the book abounds in a nauseating excess of
communist lingo. The word capitalism/capitalist in its political sense is used
220 times in this book along with a liberal dose of quotes from Karl Marx,
Lenin and even Stalin. The author claims that ‘capitalism is socially,
politically and culturally stronger than feudalism because it employs a higher
technique of production’. The sole reason behind this generalization is that
Marx said so. This book was written when Indian independence was fast
approaching and Desai’s estimation of the nation’s forward movement exposes the
lack of his perceptive rigour. He prophesies that independence,
self-determination of nationalities and socialist economic system are the
prerequisites for a complete solution of the problem of nationalities and
minorities. This is all very well until one recollects that the socialist
economic system brought the country very near to the edge of bankruptcy in 1991
and had to be disbanded on a war footing.
One
upside of the author is that he doesn’t attempt to hide his political
orientation. Right at the start, he confirms that historical materialism is the
methodology applied to his study. This book treats the various language groups
in India such as Marathas, Kannadas, Telugus or Gujaratis as separate
nationalities, but stops just short of advocating self-determination and sovereignty
to them. But the depressed classes among Hindus are treated as a ‘national
minority’ like Muslims. The author claims to follow a rational outlook and
terms like ‘superstition’, ‘oppression’ and ‘discrimination’ are freely used in
the discourse on early Indian belief systems. However, when it comes to Islam,
he takes on kid gloves and is all praise! He even compares pan-Islamism to
humanism (p.301) and argues that ‘Islam arose out of the democratic ferment of
the common people of Arabia against the privileged state of society’ (p.301). Statements
like ‘communalism of the Muslim masses in India is generated by the economic
exploitation by capitalists, landlords, moneylenders and merchants who were all
Hindus’ (p.372) provide a secular prop to the fanatical argument that divided
India. With such a partisan view in mind, Desai considers the Moplah Rebellion
in Malabar to be ‘economic in content’. At this point, he might have felt a
pang of guilt and proceeds to admit that it was ‘religious in form’.
The
book typifies the genre of leftist analysis of Indian history and society. It
is recommended with a caveat that readers should first dehusk the political
narrative to reach the kernel of truth inside.
Rating:
2 Star
No comments:
Post a Comment