Title: Economic
Sutra – Ancient Indian Antecedents to Economic Thought
Author: Satish Y. Deodhar
Publisher: Penguin Random House,
2019 (First)
ISBN: 9780670092864
Pages: 199
The field of economic theory and ancient India was long thought
to be an oxymoron as the latter was well known for its overarching spirituality
in all walks of life. References to ancient non-Western antecedents do not find
mention in mainstream literature on the history of economic thought. This is actually
an error in perception of the nature of ancient Indian thought which was secular
in all aspects affecting ordinary life. This book examines the antecedents of modern
economic thought, behaviour and policy as found in the treatises of the ancient
Indian subcontinent. This is a part of the IIMA book series on relevant economic
concepts organized by the Indian Institute of Management Ahmedabad (IIMA). It offers
an engaging perspective on ancient Indian economic thought by focusing on original
and secondary sources. Satish Y. Deodhar teaches economics at IIMA. He is the author
of the bestselling book ‘Day to Day Economics’.
The first glimpse to ancient Indian thought
was facilitated by colonial scholars who learnt Sanskrit as part of their official
work. Enquiries in the Islamic period were sporadic and few, like in the lifetimes
of Akbar or Dara Shukoh. In that sense, it was the English scholars who lifted the
veil on ancient India after a gap of eight centuries. However, they focused only
on the other-worldly stream of Indian thought. They interpreted this to be instrumental
in the denial of economic betterment and alleviation of poverty in India. Marx was
also influenced by this biased opinion, arguing that lack of class conflict prevented
India from progressing. As a sequel, Indians were stereotyped as highly spiritual
people with a fatalistic outlook. This helped to explain away the abysmal rate of
GDP growth in post-independent India as almost a genetic trait inherited from the
ancients. This was also disparagingly called the ‘Hindu rate of growth’ when the
reason for the slow growth was Nehru’s flawed economic policy which engendered an
all-pervasive, state-controlled command economy that shackled the country. When
these policies were scrapped in 1991, economic growth shot up to world standards.
Deodhar makes a detailed analysis of
ideas in ancient Indian thought that specifically deals with economic concepts.
Buddha comments householders to acquire wealth through lawful and honourable means.
He advised shopkeepers to be shrewd, alert to market conditions and to make a morally
justifiable profit (p.31). Even before that, Shukla Yajurveda recognizes four types
of commercial activities – agriculture, trade and commerce, animal husbandry and
lending at interest. Kautilya, the great political economist of ancient India argued
that the ruler must protect the choices of the people in the attainment of purusharthas (goals of man at different stages
of life), of which artha (amassing of
wealth) was the foremost in his opinion. A charming feature of this book is the
great care it lavishes on Tamil classics, which boast of a pedigree comparable to
Sanskrit. Thirukural has 700 aphorisms related to wealth. Thiruvalluvar reiterates
the Sanskrit purusharthas of dharma, kama,
artha and moksha (rightful living, accumulation of wealth, love and happiness and
salvation). The idea that wealth brings about further accession of wealth expresses
the importance of capital as an input to create more wealth.
A superficial discussion on varna and jati and the way Indian society was categorized into numerous jatis (castes) is seen in this book. Varna
system was not based on birth and Deodhar claims that it was not hierarchical (p.72).
It was the teacher who initiated his pupils into different varnas after studies
which the children underwent for many years. Megasthenes, who served as Greek ambassador
in Mauryan India mentions that all Indians were free and they did not even consider
using foreigners as slaves. This was in stark contrast to Aristotle’s world view
which held that some men are by nature slaves and that slavery is both expedient
and right. When various crafts and guilds developed, the technology had to be guarded
as a secret. This was conveniently done by way of intra-class marriages and dining
restrictions. Over time, it got cast into vocations and jatis. Law books such as
Manu Smriti caused degeneration of varna system into endogamous groups. It made
families perform upanayana (initiation)
at an early age of the child rather than a teacher performing it as a commencement
ceremony at the end of a 12-year study. The British mixed the concept of race into
jati and made them watertight in the bargain.
Any discussion on economic thought in
India would sooner or later delve into the rich compendium included in the Arthashastra
of Kautilya. Luckily, the author spends only a cursory look at the injunctions of
Kautilya. He also correlates the concepts with modern society. The ancient preceptor
recommends that taxes should be collected the way bees collect honey from flowers.
It is also seen that a large differential existed between the top and bottom rungs
of imperial jobs. The wage of a minister was 48,000 panas a year while the lowest
level public servants received only 60 panas a year. This ratio of 800:1 is an indicator
of the large asymmetry in household income. Some amount of state intervention in
trade can also be discerned in Arthashastra. It stipulates that the director of
trade is to ascertain the cost price after taking into account investment, production,
rent, interest, duty and others. For determining the sale price of goods, a 5 to
10 per cent profit for domestic and foreign trade respectively is recommended. Penalties
were in place for sale price greater than the permitted markup. Such close intervention
in the functioning of markets, if it was indeed in existence, would have resulted
in corruption rather than the common folk getting a fair deal.
‘Sutra’ is a Sanskrit word that means
a string or a thread that holds jewels together. In ancient times, philosophical
thoughts, principles and rules were expressed in the form of aphorisms and were
written on palm leaves sewn together with a thread. Thus, both figuratively and
literally, these writings were called sutras.
This book provides a bridge between the elements of pre-Kautilyan economic thoughts
and Kautilya’s Arthashastra which is the usual starting point for most researchers
on economic theory. Thus we see Panini (700 BCE) mentioning debt and repayment with
interest. The notion of expressing interest as a ‘per cent’ of the principal originated
in India. Kautilya also talks about varying interest rates for various modes of
trade. Higher interest rate was prescribed for money borrowed for risky ventures
like overseas trade.
The author claims expertise in Sanskrit
which he learned at school. This does not seem to be sufficient to extract ideas
from ancient texts. In that sense, the author’s claim that he has referred original
texts would be in doubt. Still, the amount of research Deodhar has done with secondary
sources is impressive. The book takes care not to make the discussion too technical
which would have scared the readers away. Readers are also advised not to put too
much a premium on the opinions expressed in this book as it is oriented more towards
lay people. It includes a crossword at the end in which the clues refer to concepts
enunciated in the narrative. Readers are encouraged to try it before and after reading
the book and compare the results. Though it looks like comprehension questions in
a text book, this provides a measurable parameter of the book’s utility.
The book is highly recommended.
Rating: 3 Star
No comments:
Post a Comment