Title:
China’s Crony Capitalism – The Dynamics of Regime
Decay
Author:
Minxin Pei
Publisher:
Harvard University Press, 2016 (First)
ISBN:
9780674737297
Pages:
365
When
Mao died in 1976, China was at a crossroad of her destiny. The Chairman’s
politically exhilarating but economically disastrous policies had put the
country in a fix. It was Deng Xiaoping who succeeded Mao that put China back on
rails and steered her to prosperity by scrapping ideological underpinnings and
ushering in capitalist reforms in the 1990s. However, the power to set policy
and take crucial decisions was still vested in the hands of a coterie of
powerful party bosses. With advancing decentralization that came in the wake of
Deng’s economic reforms, party chiefs in the provinces and prefectures wielded
unrestrained power and liberal delegation of authority was transferred to them.
Transparency of financial transactions and installation of an open market
mechanism to channel them were not the priorities of the party elite.
Consequently, collusion between the party officials and private businessmen
began to have a clinching effect on major economic decisions taken by corrupt
officials at all levels. This went on in the party, the government and
state-owned enterprises (SOE). Corrosion of the political authority of the
party led to regime decay. The degeneration of the administrative apparatus was
stemmed in 2012 when Xi Jinping assumed power and immediately ordered a
crackdown on corruption. As ordinary Chinese watched in disbelief, hundreds of
officials having very high ranks and their accomplices were booked and
mercilessly brought to justice. This book analyses the systematic failures that
encouraged foul play, the methods by which unscrupulous elements carried on
their murky business and the prospects of the communist party which is hampered
by the bogey of corruption. Minxin Pei is Tom and Margot Pritzker Professor of
Government and Roberts Fellow at Claremont McKenna College in the US.
Crony
capitalism is an instrumental union between capitalists and politicians
designed to allow the former to acquire wealth, legally or otherwise, and the
latter to seek and retain power. Liberal capitalism, with its appendages like
democracy and transparency, is anathema to the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) and
its cronies. Collusive corruption came to the fore in 1990s, after the
Tiananmen Square massacre in which thousands of protesting students were mauled
and crushed under the wheels of army tanks driven into the midst of the young
people in a bid to clear the square. It was one of the most horrific and brutal
acts of oppression by a regime on its citizens. Opening up of the economy reached
fever pitch after this incident because the Chinese government was anxious to
ensure a speedy improvement in the economic lot of the people and mollify them.
But collusive corruption is more destructive than individual corruption because
such behaviour destroys the organizational fabric of the state, increases the
difficulty of detection and produces greater financial gains for the
perpetrators. With the administrative decentralization came the collusion of
party chiefs and their subordinates with businessmen. Local chiefs were now
powerful enough to appoint and control the career prospects of subordinates.
Transfer of state assets to private entrepreneurs put more problems on the
table. Reforms on ownership rights under opaque regulations offered more
avenues for corruption. Real estate and land transactions, infrastructure and
construction, mining and SOE restructuring are the most corruption-prone areas
in China. However, the perpetrators of graft appear to yield as soon as they
are taken into custody. In a bid to get leniency of sentences, they make a
clean breast of it all and disclose the names and deeds of their
co-conspirators. Investigation into totally unrelated cases thus leads to
exposure in other areas. China’s judiciary is also complicit. Unlike
conventional courts of law that strive to uphold the rule of law, Chinese
judiciary is just another arm of the Communist party apparatus and functions as
an instrument of party autocracy. It is governed by a strict hierarchy of party
men who are themselves venal.
Organizational
reforms in CCP in 1984 transferred the control of an organizational unit from
another unit two levels above it to the immediately superior party committee.
This brought in the practice of maiguan
maiguan (buying and selling of offices) by which cronies could be inserted
at any level in the bureaucracy. Disciplinary inspection committees, which
controlled foul play to some extent, were weakened. The affordability of bribes
for superior positions posed another dilemma. Local officials were paid low
salaries and so couldn’t manage the required kickbacks. Such people sought the
help of businessmen and crime bosses who advanced the requisite sums. Usually,
funding for buying positions came from embezzled public funds, savings from
previous corruption income and money received from public sources. This makes
the author claim that institutional flaws of the Leninist party state is the
root cause of regime decay rather than moral failings of its individual
members.
Pei
compares the economic after-effects of East Bloc countries to China’s
experiment with the same scope and magnitude, but with the party still in
command. Transfer of state assets to individuals spawned a kleptocracy in
Russia, but this process was comparatively transparent in Poland, Czech Republic,
the Baltic States and Hungary. Appropriation of power and financial wellbeing
of the mafia-politician nexus bodes ill for the future of China especially if
the party apparatus is suddenly or violently dismantled. The author makes a
prescient warning that if a regime transition should come, the initiating event
is more likely to be a breakdown of the decaying autocracy, possibly induced by
a split among the elites inside the party-state, a devastating economic shock,
an Arab Spring-style mass revolt that the authorities fail to crush quickly, a
disastrous external adventure, or a combination of such events (p.268).
The
book is tiresome to read with its monotonous drawl of repeating data and the
author making extensive conclusions from hypothetical evaluation of the actual
cases of corruption. The entire analysis is based on a dataset of just 260
cases. Frequent and indiscriminate use of statistical concepts of mean, median and
standard deviation in analyzing the amount of wealth illegally acquired, the
tenure of prison terms awarded to the culprits and the number of years they
could carry on with their trade lends an aura of armchair intellectual exercise
to the whole book rather than providing a down to earth picture of the ground
reality. However, it must also be remembered that China is not going to allow
foreign researchers to interview its convicts in the foreseeable future. Each
chapter in the book begins with a quote from President Xi Jinping’s
anticorruption speeches made in 2013-14. Detailed appendices showing the data
on individual convictions are given, but when Pei repeatedly mention corrupt
deals and the names of perpetrators in the main text, it gets a bit tedious for
the reader.
The
book is recommended.
Rating: 2 Star
No comments:
Post a Comment